AustLII Home | Databases | WorldLII | Search | Feedback

Upholding the Australian Constitution: The Samuel Griffith Society Proceedings

You are here:  AustLII >> Databases >> Upholding the Australian Constitution: The Samuel Griffith Society Proceedings >> 2000 >> [2000] SGSocUphAUCon 13

Database Search | Name Search | Recent Articles | Noteup | LawCite | Author Info | Download | Help

Mackerras, Malcolm --- "The Inner Metropolitan Republic" [2000] SGSocUphAUCon 13; (2000) 12 Upholding the Australian Constitution 93


Chapter Ten
The Inner Metropolitan Republic

Malcolm Mackerras

Perhaps it may be best to start with these overall voting statistics of the republic referendum. First, there were 12,392,040 electors enrolled to vote and the turnout was 95.1 per cent. Second, the total formal vote was 11,683,811 and the informal vote was 101,189. That meant the total votes cast were 11,785,000. Third, there were 42 seats voting ‘Yes’ (25 Labor and 17 Liberal) and 106 voting ‘No’. In other words, majorities in 72 per cent of the seats said ‘No’. Fourth, electoral divisions voting ‘No’ covered 7,686,103 sq km and those voting ‘Yes’ 6,259 sq km. Expressed in another way, seats voting ‘No’ covered 99.9 per cent of the area of Australia and seats voting ‘Yes’ covered 0.1 of one per cent of that area.

As is clear from the above, I say that electorates voting ‘Yes’ were exclusively from Australia’s inner metropolitan areas. That is why I am calling this paper The Inner Metropolitan Republic. It needs to be admitted, however, that the Australian Electoral Commission does not define all those 42 divisions as ‘Inner Metropolitan’. Rather, it defines 27 as being such, while 13 (Aston, Berowra, Boothby, Bruce, Calwell, Deakin, Fowler, Hotham, Jagajaga, Maribyrnong, Menzies, Ryan and Scullin) are defined as ‘Outer Metropolitan’. Two seats, Cunningham and Newcastle, are defined as ‘Provincial’. For more information see Table 4, below.

In the cases of Cunningham and Newcastle the AEC description as ‘Provincial’ is very difficult to defend. I would have thought the description ‘Inner Metropolitan Wollongong and Newcastle’ would be appropriate. It is a striking fact that Cunningham and Newcastle voted ‘Yes’ while all the outer metropolitan Newcastle and Wollongong divisions (Charlton, Dobell, Hughes, Robertson, Shortland and Throsby) voted ‘No’.

In the cases of the 13 AEC ‘Outer Metropolitan’ seats which voted ‘Yes’, I can see how Ryan in Brisbane (238 sq km), Berowra in Sydney (463 sq km) and Calwell in Melbourne (234 sq km) might merit that description. However, the AEC describes both ACT electorates as ‘Inner Metropolitan’. Canberra has an area of 1,900 sq km and Fraser has an area of 535 sq km. For that reason my picture of the 42 seats voting ‘Yes’ is that every one of them may sensibly be regarded as inner metropolitan. No wonder they combine to cover only 0.1 of one per cent of Australia’s land mass!

Altogether 14 seats classified as ‘Inner Metropolitan’ by the AEC voted ‘No’. They were Banks, Blaxland (Paul Keating’s old seat), Cook, Fremantle (Carmen Lawrence!), Hindmarsh, Lilley, Moreton, Parramatta, Perth, Port Adelaide (Mick Young’s old seat), Reid, Stirling, Swan and Tangney. Still, while monarchists may rejoice at the result in a seat like Blaxland, it has to be admitted that the Queen was, as they would say, ‘done like a dinner’ throughout inner metropolitan Australia – and in every State.

Meanwhile the republic was massively rejected everywhere else.

The above observations may sound rather partisan. Tables 1 and 2 record the situation in formal terms.

Table 1: Formal Votes and Percentages for Republic Referendum

State/Territory
‘Yes’
‘No’
Total
Formal
Votes
%
Votes
%
New South Wales
1,817,380
46.4
2,096,562
53.6
3,913,942
Victoria
1,489,536
49.8
1,499,138
50.2
2,988,674
Queensland
784,060
37.4
1,309,992
62.6
2,094,052
Western Australia
458,306
41.5
646,520
58.5
1,104,826
South Australia
425,869
43.6
551,575
56.4
977,444
Tasmania
126,271
40.4
186,513
59.6
312,784
Australian Capital Territory
127,211
63.3
73,850
36.7
201,061
Northern Territory
44,391
48.8
46,637
51.2
91,028
Australia
5,273,024
45.1
6,410,787
54.9
11,683,811

Table 2: Formal Votes and Percentages for Preamble Referendum

State/Territory
‘Yes’
‘No’
Total Formal
Votes
%
Votes
%
New South Wales
1,647,378
42.1
2,261,960
57.9
3,909,338
Victoria
1,268,044
42.5
1,718,331
57.5
2,986,375
Queensland
686,644
32.8
1,405,841
67.2
2,092,485
Western Australia
383,477
34.7
720,542
65.3
1,104,019
South Australia
371,965
38.1
604,245
61.9
976,210
Tasmania
111,415
35.7
200,906
64.3
312,321
Australian Capital Territory
87,629
43.6
113,293
56.4
200,922
Northern Territory
35,011
38.5
55,880
61.5
90,891
Australia
4,591,563
39.3
7,080,998
60.7
11,672,561

Since two questions were put to the people the Preamble result is also recorded here. The fact that the formal vote was some 11,000 less for the Preamble is another way of saying that the Preamble’s informal vote was some 11,000 greater than for the republic. It can be seen from Table 3 opposite that its 45.1 per cent affirmative vote gave the republic a rank of 30 out of the 44 referendum questions put since Federation. In other words, there were 14 proposals getting less overall support than the republic which, in any event, was markedly more successful than the Preamble. The dismal defeat of the Preamble was shown by its 39.3 per cent affirmative vote, placing it at number 38 when ranked by national ‘Yes’ percentages. In not a single electorate (not even in Bennelong) was support for the Preamble greater than for the republic. Now please excuse me for writing no more about it. The less said about the Preamble the better!

If readers should wonder why only formal votes and percentages are shown, there is a good reason. It relates to the accepted interpretation of section 128 of the Constitution. The fourth paragraph of that section actually reads:

“And if in a majority of the States a majority of the electors voting approve the proposed law, and if a majority of all the electors voting also approve the proposed law, it shall be presented to the Governor-General for the Queen’s assent”.

When I first read those words (as long ago as 1951) I assumed that the ‘Yes’ vote must exceed the combination of ‘No’ and informal votes both nationally and in four States. Otherwise the proposal would be deemed to have failed. Certainly the words create that impression.

Table 3: Referendum Results Ranked by National ‘Yes’ Percentages


Subject
Date
Government
% ‘Yes’
1
Aboriginals
May 1967
Non-Labor
90.8
2
Senate elections
Dec 1906
Non-Labor
82.7
3
Retirement of judges
May 1977
Non-Labor
80.1
4
Referendums
May 1977
Non-Labor
77.7
5
State debts
Nov 1928
Non-Labor
74.3
6
Senate casual vacancies
May 1977
Non-Labor
73.3
7
Simultaneous elections
May 1977
Non-Labor
62.2
8
State debts
Apr 1910
Non-Labor
54.9
9
Social services
Sep 1946
Labor
54.4
10
Aviation
Mar 1937
Non-Labor
53.6
11
Marketing of primary products
Sep 1946
Labor
50.6
12
Terms of senators
Dec 1984
Labor
50.6
13
Industrial employment
Sep 1946
Labor
50.3
14
Trusts
May 1913
Labor
49.8
15
Legislative powers
Dec 1919
Non-Labor
49.7
16
Trade and commerce
May 1913
Labor
49.4
17
Communism
Sep 1951
Non-Labor
49.4
18
Corporations
May 1913
Labor
49.3
19
Industrial matters
May 1913
Labor
49.3
20
Nationalisation of monopolies
May 1913
Labor
49.3
21
Railway disputes
May 1913
Labor
49.1
22
Finance
Apr 1910
Non-Labor
49.0
23
Nationalisation of monopolies
Dec 1919
Non-Labor
48.6
24
Simultaneous elections
May 1974
Labor
48.3
25
Altering constitution
May 1974
Labor
48.0
26
Democratic elections
May 1974
Labor
47.2
27
Interchange of powers
Dec 1984
Labor
47.1
28
Local government bodies
May 1974
Labor
46.9
29
Reconstruction, democratic rights
Aug 1944
Labor
46.0
30
Republic
Nov 1999
Non-Labor
45.1
31
Prices
Dec 1973
Labor
43.8
32
Industry and commerce
Sep 1926
Non-Labor
43.5
33
Essential services
Sep 1926
Non-Labor
42.8
34
Rents and prices
May 1948
Labor
40.7
35
Parliament
May 1967
Non-Labor
40.3
36
Monopolies
Apr 1911
Labor
39.9
37
Legislative powers
Apr 1911
Labor
39.4
38
Preamble
Nov 1999
Non-Labor
39.3
39
Fair elections
Sep 1988
Labor
37.6
40
Marketing
Mar 1937
Non-Labor
36.3
41
Incomes
Dec 1973
Labor
34.4
42
Local government
Sep 1988
Labor
33.6
43
Parliamentary terms
Sep 1988
Labor
32.9
44
Rights and freedoms
Sep 1988
Labor
30.8

Note: Due to the majority of States requirement, all proposals supported by less than 54 per cent nationally were defeated. However, of the nine highest ‘Yes’ percentages only eight were carried. The 1977 simultaneous elections proposal was defeated because of ‘No’ majorities in Queensland, Western Australia and Tasmania.

However, I checked the records and found that in September, 1946 the social services amendment was deemed to have been carried in all six States. Yet in three States it was not true that ‘a majority of the electors voting approve the proposed law’. In Queensland the affirmative vote was 299,205, the negative vote 284,465 with 28,500 informals. In South Australia the affirmative vote was 197,395, the negative vote 184,172 with 17,734 informals. In Tasmania the affirmative vote was 67,463, the negative vote 65,924 with 11,493 informals. On an apparent literalist interpretation the social services amendment would never have been carried. It ‘failed’ in three States.

The explanation is that the relevant part of section 128 has always been interpreted as though it reads as follows:

“And if in a majority of the States a majority of the electors casting a formal vote approve the proposed law, and if a majority of all the electors casting a formal vote also approve the proposed law, it shall be presented to the Governor-General for the Queen’s assent”.

Constitutionally speaking, informal votes have exactly the same status as votes not cast at all. Therefore, let me ignore informal votes entirely. However, when I use the expression ‘the accepted interpretation of section 128’ (see above) it should be noted that at least one man will dissent from me vehemently. Mr Justice Ken Handley (Court of Appeal, Supreme Court of New South Wales) has given me details of a Scottish case in 1921 (Latham v. Glasgow Corporation) which he claims settles the argument. The judges wrote:

“In terms of subsection (3) of section 2 of the Act of 1913, the effect of the poll depends on whether or not certain percentages of the total ‘votes recorded’ are in favour of a resolution or resolutions to a certain effect. The question which is raised is: What is the meaning of the expression ‘votes recorded’?”

In brief, the judges decided the proposal had not been carried because the combination of negative and informal votes was high enough to counter the ‘Yes’ votes. When our High Court makes a similar finding in some future Australian case I shall change my analytical practices.

The 45.1 per cent affirmative vote means that the republic would have gained an overall national majority with a mere five per cent lift in its support. However, that would not have carried the republic proposal.

There are, in fact, seven different vote values in an Australian referendum. Seen from the pro-republic perspective the unfortunate fact is that, by and large, their support was greatest where vote values were least. By contrast, opposition to the proposal was strongest (again, by and large) in the States with the best vote values. A vote cast in either the Australian Capital Territory or the Northern Territory has the same value as each other. However, such a vote has the least value of all since it is counted nationally but not by State. Of the seven values, therefore, the Territory vote is the least valuable. The second least valuable vote is that cast in New South Wales. At the other extreme of value is the vote cast in Tasmania. If we combine the two votes (ACT plus Northern Territory) we get 58.7 per cent Territory support for the republic. In other words the only affirmative vote among the seven was the one with the least value! On the theory of uniform swing, a national ‘Yes’ vote of 54 per cent would have seen success for the republic. It would then have carried the four States needed for passage – Victoria, New South Wales, South Australia and Western Australia. That would have left Queensland and Tasmania as the dissenting States.

It is often asked why the Australian Capital Territory was the only jurisdiction to record an affirmative vote. Throughout this paper readers will come to understand that the ACT has every feature which would predict its high republican vote. The three

Table 4: Electoral Divisions by ‘Yes’ and ‘No’

and by AEC Description


‘Yes’
‘No’
Total
NSW and ACT



Inner metropolitan
13
5
18
Outer metropolitan
2
9
11
Provincial
2
5
7
Rural
16
16
Total
17
35
52
Victoria



Inner metropolitan
9
9
Outer metropolitan
9
6
15
Provincial
4
4
Rural
9
9
Total
18
19
37
The rest



Inner metropolitan
5
9
14
Outer metropolitan
2
14
16
Provincial
9
9
Rural
20
20
Total
7
52
59
Australia



Inner metropolitan
27
14
41
Outer metropolitan
13
29
42
Provincial
2
18
20
Rural
45
45
Total
42
106
148

Table 5: Electoral Divisions by ‘Yes’ and ‘No’ by Party


‘Yes’
‘No’
Total
Labor
25
42
67
Liberal
17
47
64
National
16
16
Independent
1
1
Total
42
106
148

main characteristics are those of residence, socio-economic status and party. The republic was always a Labor cause, and the ACT is the most strongly Labor of the eight jurisdictions. The referendum result, however, was one in which the ‘Yes’ vote was essentially an inner metropolitan phenomenon with a link to high socio-economic status. As the most Labor, most inner metropolitan, jurisdiction, with high indexes of relative socio-economic advantage, the referendum vote in the ACT should cause no surprise.

Before I leave the ACT (for the time being) it is worth noting a point from Table 6 below. The combined votes of the adjoining seats of Sydney and Grayndler give a higher ‘Yes’ percentage than the combined votes of Canberra and Fraser. The combined votes of adjoining Melbourne and Melbourne Ports give an even higher affirmative percentage. Thus we can say that inner metropolitan Labor seats in Melbourne, Sydney and Canberra provided the heartland of support for the republic.

The point about place of residence is so clear from the aggregate data that recourse to opinion poll findings has not yet been necessary in my analysis. From now on that changes. I rely increasingly on the findings of the opinion polls. I contend that the second best predictor of the vote is by political party.

On the day (6 November, 1999) of the referendum itself The Weekend Australian carried the results of the Newspoll taken on 3-4 November. Overall they showed a ‘Yes’ vote of 47 per cent, a ‘No’ vote of 50 per cent and three per cent uncommitted. That was a moderately accurate prediction of the outcome, albeit an under-estimate of the magnitude of the republic’s defeat.

Table 6: Electoral Divisions Voting ‘Yes’


Seat
AEC Description
Area
(sq km)
% ‘Yes’
Labor seats




1
Melbourne (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
54
70.9
2
Sydney (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
63
67.9
3
Melbourne Ports (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
43
65.9
4
Grayndler (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
29
64.8
5
Fraser (ACT)
Inner Metropolitan
535
64.5
6
Canberra (ACT)
Inner Metropolitan
1,900
62.1
7
Batman (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
54
61.2
8
Wills (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
52
58.7
9
Brisbane (Qld)
Inner Metropolitan
72
57.3
10
Chisholm (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
60
57.3
11
Gellibrand (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
75
56.9
12
Jagajaga (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
84
56.8
13
Maribyrnong (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
64
56.8
14
Lowe (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
53
56.6
15
Scullin (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
104
56.3
16
Kingsford-Smith (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
90
55.2
17
Bruce (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
64
54.5
18
Watson (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
33
54.4
19
Hotham (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
71
54.2
20
Calwell (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
234
53.9
21
Cunningham (NSW)
Provincial
356
53.6
22
Denison (Tas)
Inner Metropolitan
222
52.4
23
Fowler (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
53
51.9
24
Barton (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
39
51.8
25
Newcastle (NSW)
Provincial
127
51.0
Average ‘Yes’ in Labor ‘Yes’ seats

57.9
Liberal seats




1
Kooyong (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
49
64.2
2
Higgins (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
39
63.7
3
North Sydney (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
42
61.3
4
Wentworth (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
26
60.2
5
Menzies (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
116
59.9
6
Goldstein (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
48
58.0
7
Adelaide (SA)
Inner Metropolitan
66
56.4
8
Bradfield (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
98
55.6
9
Curtin (WA)
Inner Metropolitan
93
55.5
10
Ryan (Qld)
Outer Metropolitan
238
55.3
11
Bennelong (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
55
54.6
12
Warringah (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
61
54.5
13
Sturt (SA)
Inner Metropolitan
65
53.7
14
Deakin (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
59
52.9
15
Boothby (SA)
Outer Metropolitan
109
51.9
16
Berowra (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
463
51.7
17
Aston (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
101
51.6
Average ‘Yes’ in Liberal ‘Yes’ seats

56.5

Total Area of ‘Yes’ Seats: 6,259 sq kms

Total Area of ‘No’ Seats: 7,686,103 sq kms

However, the truly interesting finding is on page 8 of The Weekend Australian. It showed Labor voters as splitting 61-38 in favour of the republic (with one per cent uncommitted), while Coalition voters split 62-35 against (with three per cent uncommitted). When the votes were actually counted the results were fully consistent with such a finding.

A useful exercise is to translate the October, 1998 general election vote into the November, 1999 republic referendum. I estimate that, of those who gave their two-party preferred vote to Labor in 1998, the split in 1999 was 57-43 in favour of the republic. Of those who gave their two-party preferred vote to the Liberals in 1998 the split in 1999 was 65-35 against. Finally, I estimate that 80 per cent of the 1998 National Party vote was cast against the republic in 1999.

In the absence of opinion poll findings the data in Tables 7 and 8 might not be so persuasive. However, when combining the two I think the estimates of the preceding paragraph are highly plausible. The terms ‘Safe Labor’ and ‘Safe Liberal’ refer to all those seats above 10 per cent on the Mackerras pendulum. For example, on the Labor side the strongest ‘Safe Labor’ seat was Batman and the weakest Fremantle. For the Liberal Party the strongest ‘safe Liberal’ seat was Bradfield and the weakest Indi. (Note: reference to the pendulum is to the one published immediately after the 1998 general election. Thus Bradfield was the strongest Liberal seat. However, boundary changes made recently weaken the Liberal vote in Bradfield. Thus the strongest Liberal seat going into the 2001 general election is the Victorian Division of Murray. By the same process the strongest Labor seat is Fowler, to which further references are made below).

On the night of the referendum John Howard was made to suffer from continual sneering references by broadcasters to ‘the Republic of Bennelong’. As Table 6 shows, it was indeed the case that his inner metropolitan Sydney seat of Bennelong was one of the 17 Liberal seats to vote ‘Yes’. However, it is clear that the Prime Minister had good reason to be pleased by the results, taken overall. With the exception of ‘Safe Labor’ seats, all categories turned in an overall negative vote. It is true that ‘Safe Liberal’ seats, taken as a whole, did not vote as solidly ‘No’ in 1999 as they had voted Liberal in 1998, as may be seen by comparing Tables 7 and 8. However, taking all the 64 Liberal seats together we find that the Liberal two-party preferred vote in 1998 was 57.2 per cent, while the ‘No’ vote in those seats in 1999 was 55.3 per cent. I shall return to the case of Bennelong in due course.

Virtually every Labor member of Parliament and office-holder advocated a ‘Yes’ vote. Consequently it should have been possible for the Labor Party to do better than persuade only 57 per cent of its 1998 supporters to vote affirmatively. That failure is

Table 7: Aggregates of Two-Party Preferred Votes

by Types of Seat, 3 October, 1998

Seat Type
Number
Votes Preferring
Labor
Votes Preferring
Liberal-National
Votes
%
Votes
%
Safe Labor
36
1,826,903
67.3
886,584
32.7
Fairly safe and marginal Labor
31
1,257,986
54.2
1,060,895
45.8
Fairly safe and marginal Liberal
48
1,638,680
45.4
1,968,960
54.6
Safe Liberal
16
428,317
35.2
788,028
64.8
Independent
1
34,068
46.8
38,744
53.2
National Party
16
486,850
41.3
693,048
58.7
Total
148
5,672,804
51.1
5,436,259
48.9

Note: These aggregates are 65,223 votes higher than those of the AEC. The reason is that these totals include an estimate for the 65,223 formal votes cast in Newcastle. The AEC totals of 5,630,409 for Labor and Lib-Nat 5,413,431 are those for 147 contests only. The missing seat of Newcastle is caused by the fact that there was no Coalition candidate at the supplementary election on 21 November, 1998. A candidate for the 3 October election died before polling day.

Table 8: Aggregates of Republic Votes

by Types of Seat, 6 November, 1999

Seat Type
Number
‘Yes’
‘No’
Votes
%
Votes
%
Safe Labor
36
1,477,580
51.4
1,396,615
48.6
Fairly safe and marginal Labor
31
1,091,302
45.0
1,331,151
55.0
Fairly safe and marginal Liberal
48
1,708,956
44.9
2,099,345
55.1
Safe Liberal
16
563,859
44.1
713,874
55.9
Independent
1
27,938
36.9
47,788
63.1
National Party
16
403,389
32.9
822,014
67.1
Total
148
5,273,024
45.1
6,410,787
54.9

the essential reason why the republic was defeated. It is best illustrated by what happened in the safe Labor seats, as shown in Table 9. The right-hand column in that Table, ‘Relative Socio-Economic Advantage Rank’, is a concept to which I shall return. The correlation is clear. The greater the socio-economic advantage of the seat the more likely it was to vote ‘Yes’.

The drop from the Labor vote of 67.3 per cent in safe Labor seats in 1998 (Table 7) to the ‘Yes’ vote of 51.4 per cent (Table 8) was very far from uniform. In the inner metropolitan ‘Safe Labor’ seats of Melbourne, Sydney, Grayndler, Fraser, Canberra and Kingsford-Smith the average drop was only two per cent. At the other extremity were the 15 ‘Safe Labor’ seats set out in Table 10. Comparison of Tables 9 and 10 shows that the single most extreme case was Bonython, which turned in the highest ‘No’ percentage of all the 36 ‘Safe Labor’ seats, as well as showing the biggest defection from the Labor vote. Bonython is also the most disadvantaged socio-economically.

Table 9: ‘Yes’ Percentages in Safe Labor Seats


Seat
AEC Description
% ‘Yes’
Relative
Socio-economic Advantage Rank
1
Melbourne (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
70.9
4
2
Sydney (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
67.9
3
3
Grayndler (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
64.8
12
4
Fraser (ACT)
Inner Metropolitan
64.5
2
5
Canberra (ACT)
Inner Metropolitan
62.1
1
6
Batman (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
61.2
22
7
Wills (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
58.7
17
8
Gellibrand (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
56.9
27
9
Maribyrnong (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
56.8
14
10
Scullin (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
56.3
19
11
Kingsford-Smith (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
55.2
9
12
Watson (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
54.4
26
13
Hotham (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
54.2
10
14
Calwell (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
53.9
21
15
Cunningham (NSW)
Provincial
53.6
7
16
Denison (Tas)
Inner Metropolitan
52.4
6
17
Fowler (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
51.9
35
18
Newcastle (NSW)
Provincial
51.0
11
19
Prospect (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
49.8
25
20
Reid (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
49.0
33
21
Blaxland (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
49.0
32
22
Lalor (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
48.7
23
23
Holt (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
48.7
28
24
Fremantle (WA)
Inner Metropolitan
48.3
5
25
Port Adelaide (SA)
Inner Metropolitan
47.5
30
26
Perth (WA)
Inner Metropolitan
47.4
8
27
Throsby (NSW)
Provincial
46.9
29
28
Shortland (NSW)
Provincial
45.4
18
29
Corio (Vic)
Provincial
44.5
24
30
Charlton (NSW)
Provincial
43.7
13
31
Chifley (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
42.2
34
32
Werriwa (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
41.8
31
33
Hunter (NSW)
Rural
36.8
20
34
Brand (WA)
Provincial
33.7
16
35
Lyons (Tas)
Rural
33.5
15
36
Bonython (SA)
Outer Metropolitan
33.3
36

Table 10: Rank Order of Loss of ‘Yes’ Vote


Seat
AEC Description
‘Yes’/‘No’ Majority
Loss (a)
1
Bonython (SA)
Outer Metropolitan
No
31.2
2
Chifley (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
No
28.7
3
Brand (WA)
Provincial
No
28.6
4
Hunter (NSW)
Rural
No
27.9
5
Lyons (Tas)
Rural
No
27.1
6
Throsby (NSW)
Provincial
No
25.6
7
Fowler (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
Yes
24.4
8
Blaxland (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
No
23.1
9
Reid (NSW)
Inner Metropolitan
No
22.6
10
Lalor (Vic)
Outer Metropolitan
No
21.1
11
Werriwa (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
No
20.9
12
Prospect (NSW)
Outer Metropolitan
No
19.9
13
Charlton (NSW)
Provincial
No
19.3
14
Gellibrand (Vic)
Inner Metropolitan
Yes
19.0
15
Port Adelaide (SA)
Inner Metropolitan
No
18.6
Average
No
23.9

(a) The term ‘Loss’ refers to the reduction from the Labor share of the two-party preferred vote in 1998 to the ‘Yes’ percentage in 1999. For example, in Gellibrand in 1998 Labor had 75.9 per cent of the two-party preferred vote. The ‘Yes’ vote in 1999 was 56.9 per cent so the loss was 19 per cent.

Kim Beazley was made to suffer the indignity of losing the referendum as well as having a disastrous defeat in his own seat of Brand (see Table 9). John Howard had to put up with sneers about ‘the Republic of Bennelong’ as well as watch 17 of the 64 Liberal seats turn in ‘Yes’ majorities (see Tables 4 and 5). There was, however, one leader who had every reason to smile. John Anderson succeeded in getting every one of his party’s seats to vote ‘No’. The extent of his success is shown in Table 11B below. In only one National Party seat did the ‘No’ vote fall below 60 per cent. That was in Richmond (NSW) where the member, Larry Anthony, was a self-proclaimed republican and advocate for a ‘Yes’ vote.

Before I go on to the National Party seats, permit me an aside. Several monarchist friends of mine watched the referendum-night coverages on television. They claim to have been struck by the republican bias of the commentators. I cannot express any view because I did not see any television that night. One point should, however, be made in defence of the commentators. If it is true that repeated references were made to ‘the Republic of Bennelong’ and no references were made to ‘the Kingdom of Brand’, that could be easily explained by the fact that the polls in Brand closed three hours later than in Bennelong.

I said above that ‘I estimate that 80 per cent of the 1998 National Party vote was cast against the republic in 1999’. A major

Table 11: John Anderson—Total Success in ‘No’ Advocacy

A. Two-Party Preferred Votes in National Seats,

3 October, 1998

Seat
Votes Preferring Labor
Votes Preferring National
Votes
%
Votes
%
New South Wales




Cowper
32,002
43.6
41,335
56.4
Farrer
24,493
35.4
44,733
64.6
Gwydir
24,330
36.4
42,480
63.6
Lyne
30,650
40.3
45,451
59.7
New England
25,377
37.1
43,086
62.9
Page
35,724
47.6
39,265
52.4
Parkes
33,617
45.9
39,638
54.1
Richmond
40,013
49.2
41,270
50.8
Riverina
25,801
34.7
48,552
65.3
Victoria




Gippsland
30,445
41.2
43,506
58.8
Mallee
23,109
30.6
52,328
69.4
Queensland




Dawson
35,375
45.6
42,228
54.4
Hinkler
35,933
49.7
36,423
50.3
Kennedy
29,341
38.8
46,254
64.4
Wide Bay
33,814
47.1
37,923
52.9
Total National Party seats
486,850
41.3
693,048
58.7

B. Republic Referendum Votes in National Seats,

6 November, 1999

Seat
‘Yes’
‘No’
Votes
%
Votes
%
New South Wales




Cowper (4.2)
30,100
39.4
46,319
60.6
Farrer (1.5)
24,008
33.9
46,823
66.1
Gwydir (8.6)
19,274
27.8
50,081
72.2
Lyne (1.9)
31,045
38.4
49,785
61.6
New England (4.5)
23,328
32.6
48,203
67.4
Page (8.8)
29,925
38.8
47,213
61.2
Parkes (15.4)
22,592
30.5
51,549
69.5
Richmond (3.1)
39,208
46.1
45,790
53.9
Riverina (1.2)
25,701
33.5
51,017
66.5
Victoria




Gippsland (6.3)
27,335
34.9
51,092
65.1
Mallee (1.8)
22,395
28.8
55,426
71.2
Queensland




Dawson (14.6)
25,167
31.0
55,945
69.0
Hinkler (19.1)
22,989
30.6
52,031
69.4
Kennedy (9.0)
23,326
29.8
54,977
70.2
Maronoa (12.8)
17,944
22.8
60,610
77.2
Wide Bay (21.4)
19,052
25.7
55,153
74.3
Total National Party seats (8.4)
403,389
32.9
822,014
67.1

Note: The figure in brackets beside the name of each seat is the percentage differential between both (a) the Labor vote and the ‘Yes’ vote, and (b) the National and ‘No’ votes. In every seat the ‘Yes’ percentage was lower than the 1998 Labor percentage of the two-party preferred vote.

problem with estimating the National Party separately from the Liberals is that opinion polls typically lump the two together under the heading ‘Coalition’. Where polls do distinguish, there is a strong tendency to over-estimate the Liberals and under-estimate the Nationals because voters do not really differentiate the two. That leads typically to very small and, therefore, unreliable samples of National Party voters. In the light of Tables 11A and 11B and such opinion polling as has been done, the 80 per cent figure is highly plausible, if unprovable.

In Table 9 above there was a right-hand column headed ‘Relative Socio-economic Advantage Rank’. Questions of social class, income and occupation are essentially ones of socio-economic advantage and disadvantage. Included in the relationship also are educational attainment (or lack of it), levels of skill, property ownership (or lack of it) and race. For example, Aboriginal Australians and Torres Strait Islanders are the most disadvantaged, but renters and one-parent families are also disadvantaged. It is interesting, therefore, to measure the referendum vote against these criteria. Fortunately the Australian Bureau of Statistics has measurements of socio-economic advantage, economic resources, education and occupation. The Parliamentary Library produced, nearly a year before the referendum, its publication Socio-Economic Indexes for Electoral Divisions (Current Issues Brief, Number 4, 1998-99, December, 1998).

Back in Table 9 the 36 safe Labor seats were ranked by ‘Yes’ percentage and relative socio-economic advantage/disadvantage. The table showed that, of those seats, Bonython was the most disadvantaged (ranked at 36), Fowler the second most disadvantaged (35) and Chifley the third most (34).

It should be noted that the ranks in Socio-Economic Indexes for Electoral Divisions do not merely apply to the safe Labor seats. Of all the 148 electoral divisions, Bonython, Fowler and Chifley are the three most disadvantaged. Table 10 shows that these three electorates were striking cases of Labor’s failure to persuade its own voters to say ‘Yes’. However, a look at the other end of the scale is, perhaps, more interesting. Table 12 shows the 34 electoral Divisions with the highest Indexes of Relative Socio-economic Advantage, together with the party holding the seat and how it voted in the republic referendum. Notice the absence of Tasmania and the Northern Territory from the list. First, however, a quotation from page 2 of the publication explaining the index:

“The Index of Relative Socio-economic Advantage includes variables that measure relative social and economic well-being. Indicators included are: high income families; professional occupations; tertiary educational qualifications; dwellings owned or being purchased; dwellings with a large number of bedrooms and a large number of motor vehicles. A higher score on this index means that the Electoral Division has a relatively large proportion of people with the above attributes (i.e., high incomes, professional occupations, tertiary qualifications, etc.). Conversely, a lower score on this index means that the Electoral Division has a relatively low proportion of people with these characteristics”.

It will be noticed that 24 of the seats in Table 12 voted ‘Yes’ (16 Liberal and eight Labor) while only 10 voted ‘No’. In other words, whereas all 148 electorates Australia-wide split more than two-to-one in favour of ‘No’, the 34 ‘rich’ electorates split more than two-to-one in favour of ‘Yes’. It is no surprise to learn that all 10 negative voting, high socio-economic advantage electorates are Liberal-held. The totals for the 16 ‘Yes’-voting ‘rich’ Liberal seats (Bradfield, Kooyong, Ryan, Berowra, North Sydney, Menzies,

Table 12: Electoral Divisions with the Highest Indexes of

Relative Socio-economic Advantage

Rank
Division
Party
‘Yes’ or ‘No’
Index
1
Bradfield (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1261.4
2
Mitchell (NSW)
Liberal
No
1176.3
3
Kooyong (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1168.2
4
Ryan (Qld)
Liberal
Yes
1151.0
5
Berowra (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1149.0
6
North Sydney (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1145.5
7
Menzies (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1145.2
8
Curtin (WA)
Liberal
Yes
1143.0
9
Higgins (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1123.6
10
Warringah (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1120.2
11
Goldstein (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1111.3
12
Tangney (WA)
Liberal
No
1110.9
13
Wentworth (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1098.2
14
Canberra (ACT)
Labor
Yes
1097.5
15
Fraser (ACT)
Labor
Yes
1091.6
16
Bennelong (NSW)
Liberal
Yes
1083.7
17
Mackellar (NSW)
Liberal
No
1081.5
18
Hughes (NSW)
Liberal
No
1076.1
19
Cook (NSW)
Liberal
No
1068.5
20
Melbourne Ports (Vic)
Labor
Yes
1068.5
21
Jagajaga (Vic)
Labor
Yes
1065.6
22
Mayo (SA)
Liberal
No
1061.1
23
Chisholm ( (Vic)
Labor
Yes
1060.5
24
Moore(WA)
Liberal
No
1060.3
25
Pearce (WA)
Liberal
No
1056.8
26
Aston (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1055.4
27
Boothby (SA)
Liberal
Yes
1053.2
28
Lowe (NSW)
Labor
Yes
1052.8
29
Moreton (Qld)
Liberal
No
1048.5
30
Sydney (NSW)
Labor
Yes
1043.3
31
Brisbane (Qld)
Labor
Yes
1043.1
32
Deakin (Vic)
Liberal
Yes
1042.2
33
Sturt (SA)
Liberal
Yes
1041.7
34
Macquarie (NSW)
Liberal
No
1039.1

Note: Divisions only appearing in Table 12 are shown in italics. They are Fraser, Moore, Pearce, Moreton and Macquarie.

Curtin, Higgins, Warringah, Goldstein, Wentworth, Bennelong, Aston, Boothby, Deakin and Sturt, mean index 1118.3) were 732,045 for ‘Yes’ (56.5 per cent) and 563,303 for ‘No’ (43.5 per cent). The totals for the 10 ‘rich’ ‘No’-voting Liberal seats (Mitchell, Tangney, Mackellar, Hughes, Cook, Mayo, Moore, Pearce, Moreton and Macquarie, mean index 1079.1) were 433,024 for ‘No’ (54 per cent) and 369,564 for ‘Yes’ (46 per cent). The total votes for the eight ‘rich’ Labor seats (Canberra, Fraser, Melbourne Ports, Jagajaga, Chisholm, Lowe, Sydney and Brisbane, mean index 1065.4) were 422,615 for ‘Yes’ (61.1 per cent) and 268,608 for ‘No’ (38.9 per cent). A crude analysis might be to say that the genus ‘Yes’ voter lives in an inner metropolitan suburb of Sydney (say, in Lowe or Sydney) or Melbourne (say, in Chisholm or Melbourne Ports) or Canberra, votes Labor, has a job with a ‘high’ income, a university degree, a middle-upper occupational status, is not old and was not born in the United Kingdom.

It will be noticed that the electorates named in the preceding sentence are Labor-held. Consequently the federal member was advocating an affirmative vote. Such was also the case for most of the Liberal seats where the member was saying ‘Yes’, for example Kooyong, North Sydney, Higgins and Curtin. Perhaps the most interesting cases, therefore, are the two ‘Yes’-voting upper socio-economic advantaged Liberal seats held by the ‘arch monarchist’ members Tony Abbott and John Howard. It will be noticed that Warringah holds 10th place and ‘the Republic of Bennelong’ 16th place in Table 12 showing seats with the highest indexes of relative socio-economic advantage.

In conversations with me each of Tony Abbott and John Howard has made this claim:

“I estimate that about two-thirds of those who voted for me in October, 1998 took my advice and voted against the republic in November, 1999”.

I (Malcolm Mackerras, that is) agree with that estimate, which is based on the view that the Labor voters in that kind of seat voted so solidly ‘Yes’ that each man could claim that a substantial majority of those who had voted for him at the general election took his advice and voted ‘No’ at the referendum.

Consider the case of Bennelong, where the two-party preferred vote in 1998 had been 42,075 Liberal and 33,013 Labor. At the referendum the ‘Yes’ vote was 43,950 and the ‘No’ vote 36,508. If nine out of ten of those 33,000 Labor voters did vote for the republic then the ‘Yes’ Liberal vote would have been, say, 12,000. On that basis, in other words, probably about two-thirds of those who had voted for him at the election did take the Prime Minister’s advice at the referendum.

My analysis of voting at the 40 polling places within Bennelong and 34 polling places within Warringah does nothing to undercut the claim of either man. If we take the nine polling places within Bennelong where the general election vote was weakest for John Howard, we find the ‘Yes’ vote was 56.2 per cent compared with 54.6 per cent for Bennelong as a whole. If we take the seven polling places within Warringah where the general election vote was weakest for Tony Abbott, we find the ‘Yes’ vote was 54.1 per cent compared with 54.5 per cent for Warringah as a whole. In Warringah, however, a pattern can be found which does not exist in Bennelong. In Warringah, the further the polling place lay from the Sydney CBD the more likely it was to vote ‘No’. Thus the outlying polling places of Allambie, Allambie Heights, Beacon Hill, Brookvale, Dee Why Central, Forestville East and North Manly voted ‘No’. By contrast, Mosman West was the only inner city polling place in Warringah to reject the republic.

The seat which may be called ‘the Republic of Warringah’ is a Sydney Liberal seat with a monarchist member and it demonstrated the inner-outer polling place patterns described in the preceding paragraph. I decided to check the patterns of Griffith and Lilley in Brisbane, and Perth and Swan in Perth. All four have republican Labor members and all four voted ‘No’. (To display my lack of bias I should refer to ‘the Kingdom of Griffith’, etcetera – especially as this is a paper for The Samuel Griffith Society!) Nevertheless, all of Warringah, Griffith, Lilley, Perth and Swan have this geographic feature in common. They stretch from the CBD (or very close to it) to suburbs quite distant from it. In all five electorates, the further the polling place lay from the CBD the more likely it was to vote ‘No’. Thus on every criterion by which it can be tested, the titling of this paper as The Inner Metropolitan Republic can be justified.

Let me call the 34 seats in Table 12 the ‘Rich List’ and make two further observations about it. The first is to compare Table 12 with Table 6, which gave details of the 42 seats which voted affirmatively. That table listed 25 Labor seats voting ‘Yes’, of which only eight are also on the ‘Rich List’. (Sydney, Melbourne Ports, Fraser, Canberra, Brisbane, Chisholm, Jagajaga and Lowe). Then Table 6 gave 17 Liberal seats voting ‘Yes’, of which only Adelaide is not on the ‘Rich List’.

The second observation about Table 12 is to notice how closely it correlates with Table 13, which shows all the seats where the ‘Yes’ percentage in 1999 was higher than Labor’s share of the two-party preferred vote in 1998. Of the 34 seats on the ‘Rich List’ in Table 12, only five do not appear in The ‘Yes’ Gain Table 13. (The seats are Fraser, which voted ‘Yes’, and Moore, Pearce, Moreton and Macquarie, which voted ‘No’). Conversely there are only five seats appearing in The ‘Yes’ Gain Table which are not on the ‘Rich List’. (The seats are Adelaide, which voted ‘Yes’, and Murray, Moncrieff, Hindmarsh and Casey, which voted ‘No’).

At the other end of the scale it is possible to compile an equivalent ‘Poor List’. I have taken the 15 highest ranked (i.e., poorest) seats from the table ‘Electoral Divisions Ranked by the Index of Relative Socio-Economic Disadvantage’ from the same publication Socio-Economic Indexes for Electoral Divisions. The 15 seats on such a list comprise ten held by Labor (Bonython, Fowler, Chifley, Gellibrand, Port Adelaide, Oxley, Throsby, Reid, Blaxland and Braddon), four held by the National Party (Wide Bay, Cowper, Gwydir and Hinkler) and one held by the Liberal Party (Grey). Only two of these 15 seats voted for the republic (Fowler and Gellibrand), and in all cases the ‘Yes’ vote

Table 13: The ‘Yes’ Gain Table

Rank
Division
Party
‘Yes’ Gain
‘Yes’ % higher than Labor’s
% Labor 2PPV
% ‘Yes’
1
Bradfield (NSW)
Liberal
28.8
26.8
55.6
2
Kooyong (Vic)
Liberal
25.6
38.6
64.2
3
North Sydney (NSW)
Liberal
23.5
37.8
61.3
4
Higgins (Vic)
Liberal
23.3
40.4
63.7
5
Curtin (WA)
Liberal
18.8
36.7
55.5
6
Warringah (NSW)
Liberal
17.5
37.0
54.5
7
Mitchell (NSW)
Liberal
16.7
30.2
46.9
8
Wentworth (NSW)
Liberal
16.5
43.7
60.2
9
Goldstein (Vic)
Liberal
16.1
41.9
58.0
10
Menzies (Vic)
Liberal
15.3
44.6
59.9
11
Berowra (NSW)
Liberal
15.2
36.5
51.7
12
Mackellar (NSW)
Liberal
15.0
34.4
49.4
13
Ryan (Qld)
Liberal
14.8
40.5
55.3
14
Sturt (SA)
Liberal
11.0
42.7
53.7
15
Bennelong (NSW)
Liberal
10.6
44.0
54.6
16
Melbourne Ports (Vic)
Labor
10.1
55.8
65.9
17
Boothby (SA)
Liberal
9.3
42.6
51.9
18
Mayo (SA)
Liberal
9.1
40.1
49.2
19
Adelaide (SA)
Liberal
7.3
49.1
56.4
20
Cook (NSW)
Liberal
6.0
41.1
47.1
21
Aston (Vic)
Liberal
5.8
45.8
51.6
22
Chisholm ( (Vic)
Labor
5.2
52.1
57.3
23
Deakin (Vic)
Liberal
4.8
48.1
52.9
24
Hughes (NSW)
Liberal
4.7
44.5
49.2
25
Brisbane (Qld)
Labor
2.7
54.6
57.3
26
Murray (Vic)
Liberal
2.6
27.9
30.5
27
Tangney (WA)
Liberal
2.4
44.1
46.5
28
Lowe (NSW)
Labor
2.0
54.6
56.6
29
Canberra (ACT)
Labor
2.0
60.1
62.1
30
Moncrieff (Qld)
Liberal
1.8
37.2
39.0
31
Sydney (NSW)
Labor
1.0
66.9
67.9
32
Jagajaga (Vic)
Labor
0.9
55.9
56.8
33
Hindmarsh (SA)
Liberal
0.7
48.8
49.5
34
Casey (Vic)
Liberal
0.3
45.1
45.4

Note: Divisions only appearing in Table 13 are shown in italics. They are Adelaide, Murray, Moncrieff, Hindmarsh and Casey.

was well below the Labor share of the two-party preferred vote in 1998.

If we look back to Tables 9 and 10 we notice that Bonython and Chifley were the two seats where the Labor Party most conspicuously failed to persuade its supporters to vote ‘Yes’. In Fowler and Gellibrand, too, the failure was there – but not enough to deny ‘Yes’ a majority. What, then, are the characteristics of Bonython, Chifley, Fowler and Gellibrand (all safe Labor seats on the ‘Poor List’) which should produce such divergent results? Here again I turn to the Parliamentary Library and the publication Electorate Rankings: Census 1996 (Background Paper No. 14, 1997-98, March, 1998).

On the referendum vote, Chifley is the one closest to the typical electorate. With an Australia-wide ‘Yes’ vote of 45.1 per cent, we find Chifley on 42.2 per cent. By contrast, Gellibrand on 56.9 per cent and Fowler on 51.9 per cent were well above Australia as a whole. Bonython on 33.3 per cent was well below. It so happens that an examination of the rankings of relative socio-economic disadvantage shows Chifley as the seat among the four usually closest to the median ranking number 74. However, that is not always the case. For example, the population of Chifley is notably young. Only 5.6 per cent of its population was aged 65 years and over, compared with seat number 74 at 12.4 per cent. The median age of Chifley was 28, the third lowest in the country, whereas at seat number 74 the median age was 34. Another unusual characteristic of Chifley lies under the heading ‘Proportion of One Parent Families with Dependent Children’. The Chifley figure is 15.1 per cent, the highest in Australia. Bonython comes in third at 14.4 per cent.

The three safe Labor seats other than Chifley (Bonython, Gellibrand and Fowler) provide an interesting contrast. In Bonython only 19.9 per cent of the population was of the Catholic religion. In Gellibrand and Fowler the figures were 33.8 per cent and 32.2 per cent, respectively. The proportion of persons of non-Christian religion in Bonython was 2.5 per cent. In Fowler the figure was 20.3 per cent, the highest in Australia. In Gellibrand the figure was 9.8 per cent, the 11th highest. The proportion of persons of ‘No Religion’ in Bonython was 28.3 per cent, the highest in the country.

In terms of place of birth, Fowler was highest in Australia by proportion of persons born overseas, being the only electorate where a majority of the population was in that category. On that score the percentages for Fowler, Gellibrand, Chifley and Bonython were 51.3 per cent, 40.1 per cent, 30.6 per cent and 28.1 per cent, respectively. Every one of the top dozen electorates by birth in the United Kingdom and Ireland turned in a ‘No’ majority. Surprise! Surprise! Among these, Bonython came in at number four, the proportions for Moore, Brand, Canning and Bonython being 22.4 per cent, 19.8 per cent, 18.2 per cent and 16.3 per cent, respectively. In Chifley, very close to the median, the figure was five per cent, while in Gellibrand and Fowler the proportions were 3.7 per cent and 2.4 per cent, respectively. Gellibrand and Fowler were in the top 15 by birth in Southern Europe, Gellibrand (fifth) at 13.2 per cent and Fowler (15th) at 8.9 per cent.

However, where Fowler and Gellibrand really stand out are in the descriptions ‘Proportion of Persons Born in South East Asia’ (Fowler first, Gellibrand second); ‘Proportion of Persons Born in Non-English Speaking Countries’ (Fowler first, Gellibrand eighth); ‘Proportion of Persons Born Overseas and Australian-Born persons with Overseas-Born Parents’ (Fowler first, Gellibrand 10th, with Fowler the only electorate where more than two-thirds of the population met that description); ‘Proportion of Persons Not Fluent in English’ (Fowler first, Gellibrand third); and ‘Proportion of Persons Speaking a Language Other Than English at Home’ (Fowler first, Gellibrand ninth, with Fowler the only electorate where more than 60 per cent of the population met that description).

The inferences from the foregoing are clear. Very poor electorates like Gellibrand and Fowler will vote ‘Yes’ because of their high ethnicity and relatively high non-Christianity and (where Christian) Catholicity. By contrast, a very poor electorate like Bonython will vote solidly ‘No’ because of high proportions born in the United Kingdom and low Catholicity. Yet all three are among the four electorates with the highest unemployment rates. At the 1996 census the unemployment rates of Fowler, Bonython and Gellibrand were 17.9 per cent, 16.2 per cent and 16.1 per cent, respectively. There was only one other seat with an unemployment rate above 15 per cent, namely the National Party seat of Cowper (NSW) which, of course, also rejected the republic.

Finally I return to the title of this paper, which says it all. This was quintessentially The Inner Metropolitan Republic. A part of Sydney such as the Division of Fowler was correctly described by the Australian Electoral Commission as ‘Outer Metropolitan’. Fowler voted for the republic, however, only because of its exceptionally high ethnicity.


AustLII: Copyright Policy | Disclaimers | Privacy Policy | Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/SGSocUphAUCon/2000/13.html